Solow, Robert M.

views updated May 17 2018

Solow, Robert M. 1924

BIBLIOGRAPHY

The American economist and 1987 Nobel laureate Robert Merton Solow was born on August 23, 1924, in Brooklyn, New York. Several years after his birth, economics, in the United States and globally, launched a great leap forward after the stock market crash of 1929 had created the Great Depression that attracted able minds to the study of economics rather than physics or biology. After Solow returned from army service in Europe during World War II (19391945), he joined in this movement under the mentorship of the economist Wassily Leontief (19061999) at Harvard. Such has been Solows originality, wisdom, and energy that his imprint can be found in diverse corners of microeconomics, macroeconomics, and welfare policy.

The awarding to Solow of the Nobel Prize and the American Economic Associations prestigious John Bates Clark Medal (1961) presumably traces primarily to his seminal 1956 growth model that breathed new life into the earlier pioneering attempts of Paul H. Douglas (18921976) to explain statistically the growth of a societys real output in terms of its historical profiles of labor and of capital inputs. Because both of these time series were so positively correlated in trend, Douglass linear-log regressions had been hopelessly ill-conditioned. At Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT), where Solow became an assistant professor in 1949 and remained until retiring as institute professor emeritus in 1995, he cut the Gordian knot by introducing into the statistical analysis independent information on market-factor shares. His principal finding was the hypothesis that much of historic gain in outputs was not plausibly connected with deepening of the Capital/Labor ratio. Instead, an exogenous residual of Schumpeter-like technical innovation shifted upward total factor productivity to an important degree. A simplest Cobb-Douglas-Hicks example, à la Solow, would be Q = (1.03)tL.75K.25. It is fitting that Solow as a Harvard student in Schumpeters last lectures put the (1.03)t Schumpeterian parameter of innovation into growth theory, with emphasis upon rate of growth in total-factors productivity.

Fruitful tools of new mathematicsDantzig linear programming, Kuhn-Tucker nonlinear programming, Bellman stochastic programmingcame into wide use among economists after World War II, and Solows diverse bibliography illustrates his role as a pioneer. Besides Solows depth, his width is exemplified by his many analyses of post-Hotelling exhaustible resources. Besides putting his pen where his heart is, at Resources for the Future (a nonprofit organization focusing on the economic and social dimensions of environmental, energy, and natural resource issues) and similar organizations, Solow has put his shoulder to the wheels of conservation economics.

President John F. Kennedys Council of Economic AdvisersWalter Heller (19151987), James Tobin (19182002), and Kermit Gordon (19161976)and staff members Kenneth Arrow, Arthur Okun, and Solow set the high water mark for fruitful academic contributions to public policy in the early 1960s. In addition, Solows facile pen over the years has reviewed contemporary debates in the public press, and he has expressed criticism of prominent economists, including John Kenneth Galbraith (19082006) and Milton Friedman. But his was never an in-your-face attack. Those to the right and the left of Solow generally respected his genial argumentation.

Solows colleague at MIT and fellow Nobel laureate Paul Samuelson has dubbed Solow the Enrico Fermi (19011954) of economics. Fermi was both a great physicist-theorist and a great physicist-experimentalist; Solow has been both a creator of new theoretical economics and also one who subjected basic economic relations to statistical testing. Without his mathematical doodlings, Solow could not have been one of the wisest in the circle of Tobin, Arrow, and Franco Modigliani (19182003). Without his native DNA and mentors (Leontief, Talcott Parsons, Richard Goodwin, Abraham Wald), Solow would not have generated the wisdoms that were uniquely his.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Arrow, Kenneth, Hollis B. Chenery, Bagicha S. Minhas, and Robert M. Solow. 1961. Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency. Review of Economics and Statistics 43 (3): 225250.

Dorfman, Robert, Paul A. Samuelson, and Robert M. Solow. 1958. Linear Programming and Economic Analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Hahn, Frank, and Robert M. Solow. 1995. A Critical Essay on Modern Macroeconomic Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Solow, Robert M. 19551956. The Production Function and the Theory of Capital. Review of Economic Studies 23 (2): 101108.

Solow, Robert M. 1956. A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70 (1): 6594.

Solow, Robert M. 1957. Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function. Review of Economics and Statistics 39 (3): 312320.

Paul A. Samuelson

About this article

Robert M. Solow

All Sources -
Updated Aug 08 2016 About encyclopedia.com content Print Topic