Coase Theorem

views updated May 23 2018

Coase Theorem

BIBLIOGRAPHY

In 1960 Ronald H. Coase, who won the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1991, published his paper The Problem of Social Cost. It presents the Coase Theorem as a new perspective on external effects, particularly harmful effects. Coase formulated his theorem as follows: With costless market transactions, the decision of the courts concerning liability for damage would be without effect on the allocation of resources (1960, p. 10). This theorem floors Arthur Pigous welfare-economic approach of externalities. Since the publication of Pigous The Economics of Welfare (1920) economists were used to seeing externalities (side effects) as divergences between private and social net products. In this respect, the conventional thought is that if A inflicts harm on B, A should be restrained. The harm is a (social) cost to B, not having been taken account of in As private-cost-benefit calculation. Governmental interventions such as taxes remedy this private-social-product divergence, as a prerequisite for economically efficient decisions in the market place. This is the Pigovian approach.

The case of Sturges v. Bridgman, used by Coase, may illustrate the Pigovian approach, and shows that the Pigovian route runs into serious problems: For many years, a confectioner has had some machinery in operation on his premises. A doctor then occupies neighboring premises. After some years, the doctor builds a consulting room right next to the room containing the confectioners machinery. The vibration and noise produced by the confectioners machinery makes the doctors use of the consulting room impossible, resulting in an income loss of, say, $100. The doctor goes to court and the court orders the confectioner to refrain from using his machinery. This judgment matches the Pigovian line of thought. The confectioners production decision did not take the doctors (social) costs into account. At the same time, the sentence makes clear that considering the problem in terms of private and social products ignores the reciprocal nature. Suppression of the confectioners harm to the doctor inevitably harms the confectioner. It might be that the sentence harms the confectioner for more than $100. In that case, it is inefficient to ban the confectioners business. The social net product is less than it might be.

Coases perspective on the problem of social cost is to avoid the more serious harm (Coase 1959, p. 26). Coase formulated this starting point of his theorem in a paper preceding the Social Cost paper. In his paper, The Federal Communications Commission (1959), Coase wondered why etheric scarcity requires government regulation, whereas for other scarce means such as capital, labor, and land the American economic system uses the price mechanism. Coase identified that it is the absence of property rights in radio frequencies that blocks the use of the pricing system. Well-defined property rights for frequencies will lead to wave trade, allocating a frequency to the highest bidder. Chaos disappears; and so does the government except that a legal system to define property rights and to arbitrate disputes is, of course, necessary (p. 14).

In his Social Cost paper Coase elaborated this property-rights perspective. Referring to the Sturges v. Bridgman case, the liability sentence affects the property rights concerning the neighboring premises, and foremost defines these property rights. The confectioners liability will induce him to indemnify the doctor if his business brings him an income higher than the doctors harm of $100. Similarly, the confectioner will move his machinery if this option costs less than $100. On the other hand, if the sentence had been that the doctor had no right to stop the confectioners business, the doctor might pay the removal option, if priced at less than $100. Property rights bring about trade when mutual benefits are present. It must be said that the cost of transaction may hinder a beneficial deal. However, the Coase Theorem claims that market transactions allocate property rights to the highest bidder provided that transaction cost is zero.

Coase regretted that the zero-transaction-cost-world assumption of the theorem, in which people can negotiate their way to efficiency (Farrell 1987, p. 113), has received so much emphasis in the economics literature. People certainly do not live in such a world. Therefore, the most compelling message of the Coase Theorem is to take into account positive transaction cost in fashioning social arrangements. Key variable transaction cost should urge lawyers and legislators to identify in what manner the social net products might be increased. An elaboration of the Coase Theorem is the creation of air-polluting-emission rights. These rights induce polluters to seek emission-reduction alternatives, opening options to sell the rights profitably to the highest bidder.

SEE ALSO Externality; Overfishing; Pollution; Property Rights; Tragedy of the Commons; Transaction Cost

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Coase, Ronald. 1959. The Federal Communications Commission. Journal of Law and Economics 2: 1-40.

Coase, Ronald. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1-44.

Coase, Ronald. 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Farrell, Joseph. 1987. Information and the Coase Theorem. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 1: 113-129.

Pigou, Arthur C. [1920] 1978. The Economics of Welfare. New York: AMS Press.

Piet de Vries

Coase Theorem

views updated May 17 2018

Coase theorem

An economic theorem that is sometimes used in discussions of external costs in environment-related situations. The standard welfare economic view states that in order to make the market efficient, external costssuch as pollution produced by a company in making a productshould be internalized by the company in the form of taxes or fees for producing the pollution. Coase theorem, in contrast, states that the responsibility for the pollution should fall on both the producer and recipient of the pollution. For example, people who are harmed by the pollution can pay companies not to pollute, thereby protecting themselves from any potential harm.

Ronald Coase, the economist who proposed the theorem, further states that government should intervene when the bargaining process or transaction costs between the two parties is high. The government's role, therefore, is not to address external costs which harm bystanders but to help individuals organize for their protection.

About this article

Coase theorem

All Sources -
Updated Aug 08 2016 About encyclopedia.com content Print Topic