Cliometrics

views updated May 14 2018

Cliometrics

HISTORICAL ORIGINS

CENTRAL CONTRIBUTIONS

GENERAL CRITIQUE

BIBLIOGRAPHY

From a purely etymological standpoint, the term cliometrics should have a very broad meaning. After all, Clio was the muse of history in ancient Greek mythology, and metrics comes from the Greek and Latin word for measurement. Hence, cliometrics could encompass any application of measurement to history, placing it in the same inclusive inventory of methods as biometrics, psychometrics, and econometrics. That is, it would represent a quantitative method that does for history what the others do for biology, psychology, and economics, respectively. Yet the term is most often applied to a very specific form of economic history, namely, that in which historical data are analyzed using modern economic theory and econometric methods. By this restricted application, it may be said to constitute a specialized branch of economics rather than a method in history.

HISTORICAL ORIGINS

Although it is always difficult to assign a precise date to any intellectual movement, cliometrics is often said to have begun with the 1958 article The Economics of Slavery in the Ante-Bellum South, which Alfred Conrad and John Meyer published in the Journal of Political Economy. Whether this was truly the genesis or not, a full-fledged cliometric revolution definitely took off sometime in the 1960s. In that decade it became apparent that the practitioners of standard economic historymany of whom were strictly historians rather than economistshad to confront those who advocated what was called the new economic history. In 1960 Douglass North, an early champion of this innovative approach, became coeditor of the Journal of Economic History, the official publication of the Economic History Association. Just a few years later the journal Explorations in Entrepreneurial History (soon renamed Explorations in Economic History ) emerged as a major outlet for cliometric research. Also in the early 1960s Purdue University in Indiana became the site for annual cliometrics meetings where the new economic historians could present and discuss applications of the disciplines theory and methods to history.

Once cliometrics began to enjoy a conspicuous presence in the research on economic history, the next step was for the practice to become institutionalized as a formal subdiscipline within economics. As noted on their Web site, this step was taken in 1983 with the founding of the Cliometric Society, which was explicitly identified as an academic organization of individuals interested in using economic theory and statistical techniques to study economic history. Although the cliometrics revolution began in the United States, the movement gradually spread to other countries that featured active scholarship in economic history, such as France and Germany.

CENTRAL CONTRIBUTIONS

The single most important sign that cliometrics had come of age occurred in 1993. In that year the Nobel Prize in economics was bestowed upon Robert Fogel and Douglass North, the two most prominent researchers in the field. Fogel and North were honored specifically for having renewed research in economic history by applying economic theory and quantitative methods in order to explain economic and institutional change. This was the first time that any economic historian had received this prestigious award. Norths contributions to cliometrics went well beyond his role as coeditor of the Journal of Economic History ; he also wrote a series of now-classic volumes in the new economic history that illustrated the assets of the technique. Among these is the 1973 The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (with Robert Thomas).

Yet, in some respects, Fogels place in the history of cliometrics is even more striking. Indeed, he is sometimes described as the founder of econometric history as well as the person who actually coined the term cliometrics for the new methodology. These claims aside, it is his name that has been most strongly associated with the movement, and his involvement was apparent from the very outset of his career: His doctoral dissertation applied the innovative approach to the impact of the railroads on economic growth in the United States prior to the Civil War. This cliometric research was later published in Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History (1964). One central feature of Fogels analysis was the use of counterfactual arguments. By a detailed cost-benefit analysis he investigated how the early U.S. economy would have been affected had the railroads not been built, an assumption clearly contrary to historical reality.

Another basis for Fogels prominence is the highly controversial nature of the research he conducted with Stanley Engerman on the economic profitability of slavery in the antebellum United States. Their conclusions were published in Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery (1974). This book consisted of two volumes, the first devoted to scrutiny of the basic substantive issue, the second assigned to a detailed discussion of their data sources and statistical analyses. Because Fogel and Engerman showed that slavery was indeed profitable and that black slaves were in certain ways better off than white industrial laborers in northern cities, some critics accused them as composing an apology for slavery, that peculiar institution. Yet that accusation was unjustified. The authors were simply arguing that slavery constituted an efficient means of productionhowever morally repugnant.

GENERAL CRITIQUE

The cliometric revolution of the 1960s and 1970s was supremely successful. It began as a movement led by a few young turks against an old guard who dominated the leadership positions of the profession. Still, in less than twenty years the new economic history emerged as the prevailing approach in the discipline. Moreover, because cliometrics applied macroeconomic models and econometric methods, its proponents had much more in common with economists than with historians. As a result, departments of economics at major U.S. research universities became increasingly inclined to hire cliometricians rather than conventional economic historians. In a sense, economic historians had been replaced by historical economists, that is, by scholars who differ from their colleagues mostly in that they use older rather than newer data.

Despite this apparent success, the victory was not absolute. Although cliometrics dominates economic history in its country of origin, it has had somewhat less success abroad. For instance, at the beginning of the twenty-first century a bona fide cliometric revolution had yet to take place in German economic history. Moreover, the procedure still has its vocal critics. Some observers believe that cliometrics has relied too heavily on standard macroeconomic models that cannot capture the complexities of the economic systems being analyzed. Other critics doubt whether the available historical data can bear the weight of econometric inferences, particularly when they entail strong counterfactual arguments. Even so, it seems likely that cliometrics will continue to consolidate its presence within economic history. This prognosis is supported by the founding of the French Cliometric Association in 2001. Furthermore, in 2007 this association, in collaboration with the Cliometric Society, began publishing Cliometrica: Journal of Historical Economics and Econometric History. Hence, the growth curve for cliometrics still exhibits an upward trajectory.

At least this conclusion holds for cliometrics in its narrow meaning. If the term is used according to its broader etymology, quantitative history has made much less progress outside of economics. For instance, research devoted to the quantitative but psychological analysis of historic creators and leadersmore often called historiometrics remains a peripheral enterprise within psychology. Cliometrics may have had a more intrinsic connection with economics than it did with other disciplines that occasionally analyzed historical data. More specifically, economics is not only highly quantitative but also strongly historical insofar as change and growth are crucial components of economic theory and analysis. Hence, the supremacy of cliometrics may remain confined to economics, thereby justifying a restricted conception of the term.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Cliometric Society Web site. http://eh.net/Clio/.

Conrad, Alfred H., and John R. Meyer. 1958. The Economics of Slavery in the Ante-Bellum South. Journal of Political Economy 66: 95-130.

Fogel, Robert W. 1964. Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.

Fogel, Robert W., and Stanley L. Engerman. 1974. Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery. Boston: Little, Brown.

Golden, Claudia. 1995. Cliometrics and the Nobel. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (2): 191-208.

Greif, Avner. 1997. Cliometrics after 40 Years. American Economic Review 87 (2): 400-403.

Haskins, Loren, and Kirk Jeffrey. 1990. Understanding Quantitative History. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

North, Douglass C., and Robert Paul Thomas. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Simonton, Dean Keith. 2003. Qualitative and Quantitative Analyses of Historical Data. Annual Review of Psychology 54:617-640.

Williamson, Samuel H., John S. Lyons, and Louis P. Cain, eds. 2006. Reflections on the Cliometrics Revolution: Conversations with Economic Historians. New York: Routledge.

Dean Keith Simonton

cliometrics

views updated Jun 27 2018

cliometrics A term formed by compounding the muse of history and the concept of measurement, devised by its practitioners to describe the ‘new quantitative economic history’ which developed in the United States during the late 1950s, and rapidly became controversial in the American and European historical community. Cliometricians applied sophisticated statistical techniques (such as regression analysis) to historical data, and (to cite the example of two of the most prominent studies) attempted to calculate the profitability of slavery in the period before the American Civil War, and to quantify the contribution of the American railroads to economic growth (see R. W. Fogel and and S. L. Engerman , Time on the Cross, 1974
, and Fogel 's Railroads and American Economic Growth, 1964
).

Cliometric work was controversial, not only because of the usual distrust of (usually reconstructed) numerical data and the (occasionally questionable) use of advanced statistical techniques, but also because the most prominent studies framed their hypotheses in the novel form of explicit counterfactuals. That is, for example, they asked the question ‘What would have happened if the railroads had not been built?’ Most also rested on what were deemed to be the rather narrow behaviourist assumptions of neo-classical economics.

With hindsight, it is easy to see that the new quantitative history was not in fact all that novel, since many of the leading economists and economic historians of the early twentieth century made liberal use of quantitative historical data and neo-classical theory respectively. The use of large-scale data-sets, further encouraged by developments in computer technology, is now established practice in modern history. In contemporary usage, the term cliometrics is still commonly applied to systematic attempts to apply social science theory and statistical analyses to historical data, but it no longer describes a sharply defined school. Cliometric analyses are now found across a wide range of substantive historical subject areas.